Joseph Heath's 'Filthy Lucre'

29 posts / 0 new
Last post
Stephen Gordon
Joseph Heath's 'Filthy Lucre'

So has anyone read it? I hope so, and I hope more do. Joseph Heath is a philosophy prof at U of Toronto, and he self-identifies as a leftish type whose initial experiences with economics turned him off.

But he came back to the subject, and he managed to figure out many important things without using the mathematical tools that economists teach each other. This means that it's much more accessible to non-economists, and it still makes sense.

It's a great book, and I don't say so just because he deals with many of the themes I've dealt with here. There's an interview with him at The Walrus:

Quote:

I think over the course of the twentieth century, the Left has had a huge amount of success in terms of identifying the problems with capitalism, and kind of sounding the alarm. In other words, the kinds of issues that people have raised on the Left, along with the view that markets will not automatically fix them, have been pretty dead on, everything from race relations to environmental problems to wages... [T]he Left is extremely good at diagnosing flaws in the system, it's just that because of, often, a lack of sophistication in economic reasoning, people have invented totally crazy stories about what's actually generating these defects. And as a result, the policy prescriptions that come out of the Left are often just terrible.

 

Stephen Gordon

Could you start a different thread on those topics? I posted this in the book lounge so that we could discuss the book.

Fidel

Well the author of the book is wrong about public power vs private. The evidence across N. America and two countries is that public power is always cheaper on average than private. And deregulation is proven to be a failed market gimmick.

Fotheringay-Phipps

I read the book a few months ago and was impressed by its even-handed approach. If nothing else, it should make those of us without economic education a little more cautious about wading into discussions. It's certainly affected my view of the world: Heath makes the point that almost all social and economic programs can be seen as a form of insurance, and if they're considered as such, a lot of the heat and posturing goes out of left-right disagreements.If the book has a flaw, it's that it tends to rely too much on a priori reasoning. Like Heath's refutation of the idea that jobs are disappearing overseas, as far as I remember it now. Can't be, he says. We trade with the countries that manufacture our goods, trading our currency for theirs. Somebody has to buy our currency to keep the system stable, and whoever is buying our currency wants something we produce. Therefore the jobs are still here, they're just producing something else. QED. I'd be comfortable with a little more crude empiricism.

The writing is clear and engaging without being simplistic, and Heath occasionally lets the urbane mask slip and slashes away at those who let ideology of any stripe lead them into boneheadedness or cruelty. I awaited this book eagerly because I had so much enjoyed his previous one, The Rebel Sell: Why the Culture Can't Be Jammed, which skewered targets I am more familiar with. After you finish Filthy Lucre, go back and read that one.

It's great to have Stephen Gordon commenting on the book, and I'd like to see what he thinks about some of Heath's specific ideas.

jrootham

I read the "Rebel Sell", and then I looked at "The Efficient Society".  The problem with that was he described the advance in the well being of the Canadian working class as strictly a function of increased effiency, without mentioning labour struggles or unions at all.  The resulting shock to his credibility made reading his work make my skin crawl.  He expends a huge amount of effort in justifying the status quo.

I have reordered the books from the library for another go.  I'll have them both in about 3 weeks.

BTW Stephen, I still owe you that work on why effiency follows wages.  I started procrastinating when I got one scenario done.

 

George Victor

 

Will have to find Filthy Lucre. But Thomas Homer-Dixon's recent move from U of T to Waterloo was the result of his disenchantment with Toronto's dismissal of interdisciplinary works. And that was the situation in the mid-70s  during the early phases of our discovery that mainstream economists' dependence on limitless growth of production and consumption  was taking us down the road to environmental collapse. A couple of profs over in philosophy at the time, surmised that perhaps the human species could rely on the sort of asceticism born in early Greece to became the international ethic and save us all. These people were actually paid large salaries for such thoughts. 

Philosophy has always been allowed its head in that other-worldly way, but the old-boy alumni keeping U. of T. in Filthy Lucre would never allow thoughts of the end of growth to enter their establishments out there in the real world.  The Jeff Rubins continue to make this point.

I would expect that consideration of environmental "externalities" has not crept into the philosophical mix in the intervening third of a century...or has it Stephen? Could you give us a hint at the possibility of that breakthrough before I begin searching for the book?

 

 

Lard Tunderin Jeezus Lard Tunderin Jeezus's picture

I read nothing in the linked article which substantiated Heath's claims of sympathy or "self-identification" with the left.

His analysis is devoid of any recognition of class, and utterly ignores history. His claim that the left is without answers in the midst of economic crisis is particularly disingenuous; he ignores the consolidation of media ownership and the constant reiteration of TINA (there is no alternative) through their bullhorns.

Bookish Agrarian

Well I just ordered it from my local Library.  I'll get back to you.

Stephen Gordon

One interesting feature is that the book has a symmetric structure: the first half is of right-wing fallacies, and the second is on left-wing fallacies.

So as an extra bonus, you learn how to deal with Ayn Rand types and the Fraser Institute.

Bookish Agrarian

Now don't put me off by bringing up Ayn Rand! 

George Victor

The earlier question, SG:

 

"I would expect that consideration of environmental "externalities" has not crept into the philosophical mix in the intervening third of a century...or has it Stephen? Could you give us a hint at the possibility of that breakthrough before I begin searching for the book?"

Stephen Gordon

I don't quite know what you mean. Pollution externalities (pollution costs are borne by everyone; the gains go to only the polluter) have always been an integral part of environmental economics.

RosaL

He makes some nice points about the philosophical ignorance of economists: their ignorance of the existence of different models of rationality and the presuppositions necessarily inherent in any and all of them Smile

Stephen Gordon

Well, some of those reflect the fact that he doesn't know everything about how economists work*. But the stuff he does know is in the book and is well-written.

eta*: I think you mean that part about economists using only one model and not knowing what to do when it fails. That's most emphatically not the case: revisting assumptions and diagnosing model failure is what we do.

RosaL

Stephen Gordon wrote:

Well, some of those reflect the fact that he doesn't know everything about how economists work*. But the stuff he does know is in the book and is well-written.

eta*: I think you mean that part about economists using only one model and not knowing what to do when it fails. That's most emphatically not the case: revisting assumptions and diagnosing model failure is what we do.

 

I thought that, too, when I read it. But the whole thing makes sense if you take "models" in a broader sense. I'm not convinced that's what he's saying - but it's what I think he should be saying!

(I was also referring to what he says about the delusion that one is practicing some "pure science", without substantive political or moral presuppositions.)

 

Stephen Gordon

Again, I think that's a very crude caricature. Moreover, he makes it very clear that when you apply your morality at the wrong level, bad things happen:

Quote:
[O]ften what happens is that people apply their moral intuitions at kind of the wrong level. There's nothing wrong with having a reaction to first-order results that the market generates, but often people try to correct the problems by directly intervening at the first-order level.

 

RosaL

Stephen Gordon wrote:

Again, I think that's a very crude caricature. Moreover, he makes it very clear that when you apply your morality at the wrong level, bad things happen:

Quote:
[O]ften what happens is that people apply their moral intuitions at kind of the wrong level. There's nothing wrong with having a reaction to first-order results that the market generates, but often people try to correct the problems by directly intervening at the first-order level.

Why "moreover"? I don't see that what he says about not applying your morality at the wrong level is inconsistent with the argument (or statements) you are disputing. 

p.s. I have to go now so I'll have to let you have the last word for awhile, assuming you yourself are still here. 

 

Stephen Gordon

Somewhere in there is an implication that economists are amoral, but that's clearly wrong - which would be screamingly obvious to anyone who had ever read what economsts write. (A recurring problem is that too many people have formed their opinions about economics and economists based on what non-economists say about us.) What may be different about how we work is we apply our morality to outcomes, not to the assumptions that we make about how the world works. Wishful thinking is not usually a way of advancing our understanding.

RosaL

Stephen Gordon wrote:

Somewhere in there is an implication that economists are amoral, but that's clearly wrong - which would be screamingly obvious to anyone who had ever read what economsts write. (A recurring problem is that too many people have formed their opinions about economics and economists based on what non-economists say about us.) What may be different about how we work is we apply our morality to outcomes, not to the assumptions that we make about how the world works. Wishful thinking is not usually a way of advancing our understanding.

 

No, no, no! ARghh. I am beginning to suspect that you don't understand the critique Frown   But I really do have to go now ..... I'll be back. 

Stephen Gordon

I'll be here.

George Victor

Stephen:

 "I don't quite know what you mean. Pollution externalities (pollution costs are borne by everyone; the gains go to only the polluter) have always been an integral part of environmental economics."

Pollution cleanup, Stephen, adds to the GDP which, for economists, is a "good", a positive feature. Growth is "good", always, even on a finite planet Earth. Even cleaning up the Tar Sands operations after the destruction of the Mackenzie watershed and acid rain destruction downwind in Saskatcheway. All this will add to the GDP and will be an economic "good".

 

 From which comes a second question: How does economics come to terms with the need to end growth of the economy - and does your author break ground here?

We need to turn production and consumption habits around very quickly now, Stephen. Does your philosopher-economist enter into that discussion?

Stephen Gordon

There's nothing in the way of new ground in the book; it's an introduction to some basic ideas and how to think through these things.

Unionist

Stephen Gordon wrote:

Somewhere in there is an implication that economists are amoral, but that's clearly wrong - which would be screamingly obvious to anyone who had ever read what economsts write.

Agreed. What I have discerned is not an absence of morals, but rather the too frequent exchanging of one set for another.

Quote:
(A recurring problem is that too many people have formed their opinions about economics and economists based on what non-economists say about us.)

That's an interesting argument from authority. If economists can't convince non-economists of the soundness and social value of their work, then perhaps they should invest in the purchase of a mirror.

Quote:
What may be different about how we work is we apply our morality to outcomes, not to the assumptions that we make about how the world works. Wishful thinking is not usually a way of advancing our understanding.

Interesting dichotomy between "how the world works" and "morality". For some of us, our morality is not "wishful thinking", nor is it some freely chosen and just as freely discarded set of values or "beliefs", but rather a way of life which emerges from the actual physical and social conditions into which we are born. How, then, does an economist conceptually set one's morality to the side while examining "how the world works"? Of course, if one's beliefs conflict with one's observations, it is observed reality that must prevail. But your neat divorce of the two, in the stage of investigation and analysis, brings me back to my first point.

 

George Victor

Stephen:

 

"There's nothing in the way of new ground in the book; it's an introduction to some basic ideas and how to think through these things.

 

Looks like I'm gonna finish Walter Isaacson's Einstein, another time around, and perhaps a few more assorted volumes putting forward people of sound morals and ideas, before I get over to Filthy Lucre.

It's just that I'm more into reading these days that might hold a clue as to how my grandaughter will survive the hand-me-down civilization we leave for her.

Bookish Agrarian

Well I said I would get back and I will.

I have started this book.  Already though I am losing faith that there is much of value in the book having already huge holes in the arguments and at least one factual error.

In the introduction Heath tries to make the case that from an economic standpoint recycling paper is in fact bad for the planet.  He states that the trees used in pulp and paper are a cash crop - presumably like wheat - and that recycling causes a disincentive to re-plant.  He misses the fundamental point that trees are not simply in fields, they are in forests.  Forest ecosystems are dependent upon those trees.  Many of the best suited trees for pulp and paper are in vast tracks of land in northern areas.  There is already a massive economic discinsentive to re-plant because the area seems so big and could never be used up.  A falsehood, but one that persists. 

In the end his argument is very unconvincing and ignores all but the dollar and cents arguments all to prevelant in what he thinks he is critiquing and has been through out the book so far.  His introductory bit about lung cancer is frankly stupid and ignores the reality of the costs of carrying for someone with lung cancer and the horrible way in which you die with lung cancer essentially drowning in your own bodies fluids as if that had no 'cost'

I have yet to finish the book, but already I found one factual area in an area I guess I could be considered a bit of an expert.  The book makes the claim that agricultural cooperatives, such as say a diary one, buy under market value from their farmer members and then make up the difference through dividends.  He specificially uses dairy as an example.   In the supply managed Canadian context this is completely unfactual.  Under Canada's system of supply management in dairy, chicken and eggs farmer cooperatives, like everyone else must meet a certain floor price.  The success of cooperatives comes from farmers being able, by pooling their capital and basically signing non-compete agreeements with each other through the co-opt are able to capture a greater share of the food retail dollar.  Instead of passing on the profits beyond thier farmgate farmer cooperatives eliminate the parisite middle-men that are responsible for most of increases we see in food costs.

Any discussion around agriculture in the Canadian context that doesn't include supply management as a fundemental part of that discusssion is worthless and will end up being completely wrong.  As well and discussion of agriculture in the Canadian context that leaves out issues like captive supply and market strangleholds is also missing wide of the mark.

I agree with his fundamental assertion that people should be far more economically literate, but on the whole I find his arguments around specific fallicies unconvincing and consumed by an orthodoxy that does not exist outside the confines of books and classrooms.   It is still however, worth the read if only to point out that even something that is well written and entertaining and preports to be accessible economics can still be grounded in so much claptrap as to make the real understanding of economic forces no easier.

Anyway I made the promise to get back and have done so. 

Ta ta

Caissa

Just picked it up at the campus bookstore. I can't wait to dive in never having taken an economics course.

ETA: One of the Economics profs on campus, Rob Moir, runs for the NDP in Conservative Rob Moore's riding.

George Victor

He can't see the forests for the trees eh, chaps?  Good start.

Frustrated Mess Frustrated Mess's picture

I really resisted saying that. George. Glad you did though ... :)

Frustrated Mess Frustrated Mess's picture

Bookish Agrarian wrote:

Well I said I would get back and I will.

I have started this book.  Already though I am losing faith that there is much of value in the book having already huge holes in the arguments and at least one factual error.

In the introduction Heath tries to make the case that from an economic standpoint recycling paper is in fact bad for the planet.  He states that the trees used in pulp and paper are a cash crop - presumably like wheat - and that recycling causes a disincentive to re-plant.  He misses the fundamental point that trees are not simply in fields, they are in forests.  Forest ecosystems are dependent upon those trees.  Many of the best suited trees for pulp and paper are in vast tracks of land in northern areas.  There is already a massive economic discinsentive to re-plant because the area seems so big and could never be used up.  A falsehood, but one that persists. 

In the end his argument is very unconvincing and ignores all but the dollar and cents arguments all to prevelant in what he thinks he is critiquing and has been through out the book so far.  His introductory bit about lung cancer is frankly stupid and ignores the reality of the costs of carrying for someone with lung cancer and the horrible way in which you die with lung cancer essentially drowning in your own bodies fluids as if that had no 'cost'

I read the introduction to my wife and I asked her, how can a man so literate and educated, and a philiosopher to boot, could so miss that plantations and forests are not the same thing. That ecosystems are more than the sum of their harvestable parts. Has he never ventured into both a forest and tree farm to see the difference?  She answered that they view the world in terms of simple equations where value is assigned on the basis of selfish utility. For example, an economist sees a tree and places a monetary value on it for the paper or lumber it can produce for the purposes of profit. The economist does not value, or place a price, on the value of the tree for the services it provides to the ecosystem as a whole in terms of flood control, erosion control, habitat, shade, CO2 sequesteration, atmosphere improvement, and sustenance if it produces a fruit (to other species as well as humans). None of this matters to the economist nor the authors of the book. For that reason, the authors don't see forests and ecosystems but trees and paper.